丹尼尔·格罗斯, 美国制造业的衰落不应归咎于中国

丹尼尔·格罗斯 Daniel Gros 

博科尼大学实践教授,兼博科尼大学欧洲政策制定研究所所长。

2020 - 2022 年,担任欧洲政策研究中心 (CEPS) 的杰出研究员和董事会成员。

2000 年起担任 CEPS 董事。
Daniel Gros 

Professor of Practice at Bocconi University and Director of the Institute for European Policymaking at Bocconi University. 

2020 and 2022 he was Distinguished Fellow and Member of the Board of the Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS). 

Since 2000, was the director of CEPS.

美国制造业的衰落不应归咎于中国

来源:参考消息 - 

世界报业辛迪加网站7月11日刊登题为《中产阶级贸易政策救不了美国制造业》的文章,作者是意大利博科尼大学欧洲决策研究所所长丹尼尔·格罗斯。全文摘编如下:

美国拜登政府已经背弃了自由贸易政策,声称几十年的全球化没有让美国制造业工人受益。

美国的贸易政策即将发生重大转变。总统国家安全事务助理杰克·沙利文近日在布鲁金斯学会发表演讲时,概述了美国政府的战略——寻求“建立更公平、更持久的全球经济秩序”。这一新战略的核心意思是,尽管全球过去几十年一直从自由贸易中受益,但美国工人却没得到什么好处。

沙利文提出的第一个证据是“美国的工业基础已经被挖空”。虽然大多数分析人士把重点放在制造业占国内生产总值(GDP)的比重下降上,但制造业的下降也反映在美国贸易的构成上。本世纪初前后,制成品占美国商品出口的80%以上。到2022年,这一比例降至60%以下。

全球化和自由贸易不大可能是美国贸易中这种去工业化现象的主要催化剂。毕竟,制造业在欧盟出口中所占的比重接近80%。与其他主要发达出口国相比,美国是特例。这也意味着中国作为世界头号制造业强国的崛起并非美国制造业出口相对下降的原因。

一个更合理的推动因素是能源价格高企和能源产量的增加——尤其是石油和天然气——的共同作用。石油和天然气的产出首先解决了美国能源进口问题,随后又成为美国的另一个出口创收来源。经济学家将这一现象称为“荷兰病”,源自荷兰出现的一个现象。在1959年发现天然气田后,荷兰制造业开始下滑。

虽然能源价格已经从2022年的峰值回落,但仍处高位,尤其是天然气价格。预计,原油、精炼油和天然气仍将是美国出口产品的前三名,汽车和半导体分别占第四和第五的位置。

美国经济还受益于强劲的服务业,其中包括占据行业霸主地位的硅谷巨头。

在过去20年里,这种转变导致生产性资源越来越多地流向资源开采和服务业,制造业受到排挤。许多欧洲人羡慕美国的页岩能源繁荣和科技产业的兴盛,但美国在这些领域称霸的另一面是国内制造业的相对衰落。

因此,经常被提到的所谓中国进口商品的增加导致美国本土的失业增多和社会衰退的说法是一种误导。美国不断从中国进口制成品是因为页岩气生产和科技繁荣令国民收入和消费都不断增加。中国进口产品的出现只是这一大趋势的现象之一,而不是构成美国国内挑战的根源。美国制造业的衰落不应归咎于中国。r显而易见的是,仅通过贸易政策的改变重振美国制造业将是极其困难的。针对特定商品或类别的关税政策效果有限。有鉴于此,拜登政府并没有增加新的关税,虽然它还是保留了特朗普时期的制裁措施。现在的美国决策者似乎更喜欢把“买美国货”政策作为他们的首要工具,但拜登签署的《通胀削减法案》证明了这一做法的局限性。

《通胀削减法案》的一个目标是,为美国打造一个对电池以及可再生能源生产至关重要的矿产基地。这意味着加强资源开采而不是制造生产。但是,鉴于资源开采是资本密集型产业,需要的劳动力较少,这与创造更多制造业就业岗位的目的是不一致的。除了关税和本地生产要求之外,这项贸易政策对保护美国制造业几乎没有任何作用。

沙利文认为自由贸易没有为美国工人带来好处,在这一点上,他也许是对的。但拜登政府所谓的“中产阶级贸易政策”能否显著改善中产阶级的处境却值得怀疑。

 

针对中产阶级的贸易政策无法拯救美国制造业


https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/biden-trade-agenda-will-not-bring-back-american-manufacturing-jobs-by-daniel-gros-2023-07

2023 年 7 月 11 日 丹尼尔·格罗斯

拜登政府背弃了自由贸易,认为几十年来的全球化并没有让美国制造业工人受益。 这也许是真的,但其关于“更公平、更持久”的国际经济秩序的新计划不太可能改善他们的工资或就业前景。

米兰 — — 美国贸易政策正处于重大转变的风口浪尖。 最近在布鲁金斯学会的一次演讲中,乔·拜登总统的国家安全顾问杰克·沙利文概述了政府“建立一个更公平、更持久的全球经济秩序”的战略。 这种新方法的核心是相信,尽管世界在过去几十年里从自由贸易中获益,但美国工人却受到了不公平的待遇。

沙利文的第一个证据是“美国的工业基础已经被掏空”。 虽然大多数分析师关注的是制造业占 GDP 份额的下降——2021 年为 11%,而 1953 年为 28.1%,但制造业的下降也反映在美国贸易构成中。 世纪之交左右,制成品占美国商品出口的80%以上。 到2022年,这一比例已缩减至60%以下。

全球化和自由贸易不太可能是美国贸易去工业化的主要催化剂。 毕竟,欧盟制造业的出口份额仍接近 80%,中国则徘徊在 93-95% 左右。 与其他主要发达出口国相比,美国是一个例外。 这意味着中国崛起为世界领先的制造业强国并不是美国制造业出口相对下降的原因。

一个更合理的驱动因素是高能源价格和能源产量增加的结合,特别是石油和天然气,它首先取代了进口,然后为美国提供了替代的出口收入来源。 经济学家将这种现象称为“荷兰病”,因 1959 年发现天然气田带来暴利和货币快速升值后,荷兰制造业出现衰退,因而得名。

尽管能源价格已较 2022 年的峰值有所回落,但仍处于高位,尤其是天然气。 因此,预计原油、精炼石油和天然气仍将是美国三大出口产品,汽车和半导体分别占据第四和第五位。

美国经济还受益于强劲的服务业,包括硅谷巨头无与伦比的主导地位,这代表了快速扩大的出口收入来源。 目前,服务出口几乎与制造业出口持平,而且美国目前在服务贸易方面拥有大量且不断增长的顺差。

在过去的二十年里,这种转变导致越来越多的生产资源流向资源开采和服务业,从而挤出了制造业。 许多欧洲人羡慕美国的页岩能源繁荣和蓬勃发展的科技产业。 但美国在这些领域占据主导地位的另一面是国内制造业的相对下滑。

因此,经常被引用的说法是,来自中国的进口增加导致美国腹地出现部分失业和社会衰退,这种说法具有误导性。 美国从中国进口制成品的增加是因为页岩油和科技的繁荣促进了国民收入和消费。 中国的进口只是这一总体趋势的表象,而不是国内挑战的根源。 欧盟是一个比美国开放得多的经济体,没有经历过“中国冲击”造成的同样的社会混乱和制造业空心化——这进一步证明中国不应为美国制造业的衰退负责。

事实是,没有任何一个因素可以完全解释像制造业衰退这样的复杂现象。 在发达国家,用于商品生产的经济份额经历了长期下降。 美国的与众不同之处在于该行业对出口的贡献。 其他美国特有的因素,例如美国教育体系的状况以及缺乏培训工人进行体力劳动的学徒计划,也可能发挥了作用。 但这种转变主要是由宏观经济力量推动的。

明显的含义是,通过贸易政策重振美国制造业将极其困难。 针对特定商品或类别的关税效果有限,美国前总统唐纳德·特朗普对中国进口商品征收贸易关税就证明了这一点。 因此,拜登政府不考虑实施新的措施,尽管它保留了从特朗普那里继承的措施。

今天的政策制定者似乎倾向于将“购买美国货”政策作为他们的主要工具。 但拜登的标志性立法《减少通货膨胀法案》(IRA)说明了这种方法的局限性。

IRA 的目标之一是为某些被认为对电池和可再生能源生产至关重要的矿物建立美国工业基地。 这将需要加强与制造业相关的资源开采。 但是,鉴于资源开采是资本密集型的,并且需要较少的工人 — — 与制造业的 1100 万工人相比,大约需要 50 万 — — 依赖它与创造更多的制造业就业机会是不一致的。

为了抵消对矿物开采的支持,爱尔兰共和军对国内电池生产提供了慷慨的补贴,以及对电动汽车和可再生能源的本地含量要求。 但是,除了关税和本地含量要求之外,贸易政策对保护美国制造业几乎无能为力。

此外,任何通过获得廉价能源来促进美国制造业复苏的尝试都会给宏观经济带来阻力。 较低的能源成本可以为美国制造业提供暂时的优势。 但从长远来看,直接出口廉价能源总是比用其生产制成品更有利可图,因为廉价能源的收入会推高收入和工资。 值得记住的是,荷兰制造业的萎缩是因为——而不是尽管——拥有丰富的天然气。

沙利文的观察可能是正确的,即自由贸易并没有给美国工人带来好处。 但拜登政府的“针对中产阶级的贸易政策”能否显着改善他们的处境值得怀疑。

A Trade Policy for the Middle Class Will Not Save US Manufacturing

https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/biden-trade-agenda-will-not-bring-back-american-manufacturing-jobs-by-daniel-gros-2023-07

 

The Biden administration has turned its back on free trade, arguing that decades of globalization have not benefited US manufacturing workers. That may be true, but its new plan for a “fairer, more durable” international economic order is unlikely to improve their wages or job prospects.

MILAN – US trade policy is on the cusp of a major transformation. In a recent speech at the Brookings Institution, Jake Sullivan, President Joe Biden’s national security adviser, outlined the administration’s strategy to “build a fairer, more durable global economic order.” At the heart of this new approach is the belief that, although the world has reaped the benefits of free trade over the past several decades, American workers got a raw deal.

Sullivan’s first piece of evidence is that “America’s industrial base had been hollowed out.” While most analysts focus on manufacturing’s declining share of GDP – 11% in 2021, compared to 28.1% in 1953 – the decline of manufacturing is also reflected in the composition of US trade. Around the turn of the century, manufactured goods accounted for more than 80% of US merchandise exports. By 2022, this share had shrunk to below 60%.

It is unlikely that globalization and free trade were the primary catalysts of this de-industrialization of US trade. After all, manufacturing’s share of exports has remained close to 80% for the European Union and hovers around 93-95% for China. Compared to other major developed exporters, the US is an outlier. This implies that China’s rise as the world’s leading manufacturing powerhouse is not the cause of the relative decline in US manufacturing exports.

A more plausible driver is the combination of high energy prices and the increase in energy production, particularly oil and natural gas, which first supplanted imports and then provided the United States with an alternative source of export earnings. Economists refer to this phenomenon as the “Dutch Disease,” named for the decline of manufacturing in the Netherlands after the discovery of natural-gas fields in 1959 led to windfall profits and rapid currency appreciation.

While energy prices have come down from their 2022 peak, they remain elevated, especially for natural gas. Crude and refined petroleum and natural gas are thus expected to remain the top three US export products, with automobiles and semiconductors occupying the fourth and fifth spots, respectively.

The US economy also benefits from a robust services sector, including the unrivaled dominance of Silicon Valley giants, which represents a rapidly expanding source of export earnings. Services exports are now almost on par with manufacturing exports, and the US currently runs a large and growing surplus in services trade.

Over the past two decades, this shift has led to an increasing share of productive resources going toward resource extraction and services, crowding out manufacturing. Many Europeans envy the US for its shale-energy boom and thriving tech industry. But the flip side of US dominance in these sectors was the relative decline in domestic manufacturing.

Thus, the frequently cited claim that increased imports from China led to pockets of unemployment and social decline across the American heartland is misleading. The rise in US imports of manufactured goods from China occurred because the shale and tech booms boosted national income and consumption. Chinese imports were a symptom of this general trend rather than the root cause of domestic challenges. The EU, a much more open economy than the US, has not experienced the same social dislocations and hollowing out of manufacturing as a result of the “China shock” – further evidence that China is not to blame for the decline of US manufacturing.

The fact is that no single factor can fully explain a complex phenomenon like the decline of manufacturing. The share of the economy devoted to the production of goods has undergone a secular decline across the developed world. What sets the US apart is the sector’s contribution to exports. Other US-specific factors, such as the state of the American education system and the absence of apprenticeship programs to train workers in manual tasks, may have also played a role. But this shift was driven primarily by macroeconomic forces.

The obvious implication is that reviving US manufacturing through trade policy will be extremely difficult. Tariffs targeting specific goods or categories have only limited effectiveness, as evidenced by former US President Donald Trump’s trade tariffs on imported Chinese goods. For this reason, the Biden administration is not considering imposing new ones, although it has retained those inherited from Trump. Today’s policymakers seem to favor “Buy American” policies as their primary tool. But the Inflation Reduction Act (IRA), Biden’s signature legislation, illustrates the limits of this approach.

One goal of the IRA is to establish a US industrial base for certain minerals deemed critical for the production of batteries and renewable energy. This would entail strengthening resource extraction relative to manufacturing. But, given that resource extraction is capital-intensive and requires fewer workers – roughly 500,000 compared to the manufacturing sector’s 11 million – relying on it is inconsistent with creating more manufacturing jobs.

To offset the support for mineral extraction, the IRA includes generous subsidies for domestic battery production, along with local content requirements for electric vehicles and renewables. But, apart from tariffs and local content requirements, there is very little that trade policy can do to protect the US manufacturing sector.

Moreover, any attempt to foster a resurgence of US manufacturing through access to cheap energy will create its own macroeconomic headwinds. Lower energy costs could provide US manufacturing with a temporary advantage. But in the long run, it will always be more profitable to export cheap energy directly rather than use it to produce manufactured goods, because the income from cheap energy will drive up incomes and wages. It is worth remembering that the Dutch manufacturing sector shrank because of – not in spite of – an abundance of natural gas.

Sullivan may have been correct in his observation that free trade has not delivered for American workers. But it is doubtful that the Biden administration’s “trade policy for the middle class” will significantly improve their situation.

登录后才可评论.